A total fertility rate of 1.5 is about two-thirds that required for
population replacement. Australia’s current rate of 1.75 (and falling)
is not far above that critical point. Debate about these trends is
overdue, both here and elsewhere.
Many countries have fallen below this figure. Demographically speaking,
Japan, Russia, Germany, Greece, Italy, Spain and most of Eastern Europe
are in deep trouble. Some well past the point of no return.
Governments and intellectuals – so long focussed on the problem of
world overpopulation – have been slow to come to terms with these
trends. Now that they are starting to do so, we lack good theories to
guide future policy. Policy inaction is clearly no solution. We are having
to scramble to make sense theoretically of something that was never
expected to happen.
Advertisement
Why should so many countries be heading towards demographic
self-destruction? We can understand war, economic depression, and
political repression cutting into reproduction. But all of these countries
are at peace, and in many cases living standards (especially in health)
have been rising, while civil and political liberties are expanding.
Socio-economic and socio-political explanations thus seem wide of the
mark.
The most commonly-heard account today is that fertility falls with
modernisation, as women are freed from religious imperatives, as they get
better educated, as work takes precedence over family, and as the Pill
makes childbearing optional.
On this view women today are having the number of children they always
wanted to have. Falling fertility is simply the exercise of reproductive
free choice, for the first time in history, and if this means risking
depopulation then so be it, since there is no turning back. Pro-family
financial incentives – baby bribes – simply won’t work because
better-educated modern women won’t be bribed. For convenience, let’s
call this the modernisation model.
This is a widely held view, but how well does it fit the evidence?
Start with the cross-national comparisons. We tend to focus on societies
like our own, but in fact the English-speaking societies – Australia,
the UK, the US, Canada and New Zealand – are all above the 1.5 mark
(though barely so, in Canada’s case), so they are not yet in crisis
mode.
These societies have also been relatively migrant-friendly, which has
boosted their fertility and rejuvenated their age structures somewhat. So
migration policy has to be an integral part of this debate.
But it is only part of the story. Migration is unable to solve the
problem of fertility rates that have fallen below the 1.5 mark. As
demographer Peter McDonald observes: "Replacement migration and
increases in labour force participation rates can be successful ways to
avoid hyper-ageing, but only if fertility is in the range of about 1.6 to
2.0 births per woman."
Advertisement
The worst cases of fertility free-fall are not in Western Europe, but
in East Asia, in southern Europe, and in the ex-Communist states of
Eastern Europe – in most cases societies still close to their
agricultural pasts.
What about the trends across time? Does the modernisation theory fit
the facts diachronically? Take the Australian case. The twentieth century
saw three phases in fertility: a steady fall from four children per family
in 1910 to two in 1935; then an upswing from two to 3.5 in 1965 (the baby
boom); and since that time another and deeper fall, from 3.5 in 1965 to
1.75 today. That is: bust, boom, bust.
Any good explanation will fit all three phases. The Pill came onto the
market around 1965, and so perfectly matches the post-1965 fall. This neat
fit may be deceptive. The contraceptive story in no way explains the
previous two phases of bust and boom. Some better account is at least
worth seeking.
The modernisation story also supposes that contemporary families regard
current fertility rates as close to optimum, but the survey evidence is
against this. Women today say they would prefer to have more children than
in fact they do have.
On three counts, then, the standard story is implausible. Is there an
alternative? No credible account can leave out the pervasively destructive
contribution of the ageing welfare state.
The European welfare states long ago ceased to be family-friendly
havens. Today their first priority is very clear. In Italy, 14 per cent of
GDP goes to old age pensions. Incredibly, post-Communist Poland goes even
further, giving 21 per cent.
Poland and Italy lead the way: the OECD average is around 10 per cent.
By way of comparison, the Australian figure is a mere 3-4 per cent. In
Greece, age pensions are worth more than 100 per cent of wages. Other
countries are not far behind.
These systems are indeed "generous" – for some. That is to
say, they are seriously inequitable. In southern Europe, families with
children get very little public support, and those northern European
states such as Sweden that do support children also run very high tax
rates to pay for this support, so that most of this is of little or no net
real benefit to the recipients.
Everywhere there is upwards redistribution, from the poorer young to
the richer elderly. It is a practice that makes no sense, either
economically or in equity terms, but it is too deeply entrenched
politically to be open to effective challenge.
This inequity has to be seen in a generational perspective. The modern
welfare state’s first generation – those born in the 1920s and 1930s
– has been the only generation to make real gains from the welfare
bargain. Economist Lester Thurow notes that "In Sweden the generation
that retired in the 1960s got six times as much as they paid into the
system but the generations that will retire after 2010 are expected to get
less than 80 per cent of what they paid in."
This is far from atypical. Pioneering generational analysis by David
Thomson shows that New Zealand couples born in the 1930s will get a four-
or five-fold "return" on their lifetime taxes from public
expenditure, whereas those born in the 1950s will get something less than
a one-for-one return, and those born later still will get less still.
I estimate that the comparable disparities in Australia are less marked
but still not inconsiderable. Australia, with its lean and mean approach
to age support, is possibly the most equitable, in intergenerational
terms, of all modern states – but this is not to say that it is at all
equitable.
The European welfare systems are also unwise and unsustainable. Thurow
has observed that unfunded pension liabilities are around 200 per cent of
GDP in many OECD countries. He adds that "In Western Europe today’s
programs for the elderly will take 50 per cent of the GDP by 2030. In
Eastern Europe the problems are even worse, since the Communists were even
more generous with their promises to the elderly." We can safely say
that this 50 per cent mark will never be reached, since no society could
function with such a burden.
The present intergenerational imbalances, most strikingly in Europe,
cause about as much dysfunction as any society can tolerate. The
dysfunction is evident most of all in the lives of young families, now
required to support the elderly through taxation while raising children
without public assistance. The implications are simple and stark: they
must either work much more, or cut back on childbearing, or both. And so
they do. As Thomson puts it, "Many of the changes in early adult life
which account for this decline [in fertility] – staying at home with
parents longer, not marrying, putting off having children, having fewer
children once married – can be viewed as ‘rational’ adaptations by
young adults to declining circumstances." When fertility rates fall
below replacement, children become "public goods", but they are
goods whose scarcity is brought about by incentive structures that
militate against child-rearing.
It was not always like this, of course. In the first few decades after
1945 welfare states everywhere were child-friendly, incredibly so by today’s
standards. Indeed, that was their reason for being. Parents paid little or
no tax, and often child deductions put them into negative tax territory.
Family subsidies were widespread for health, education, and housing. And
fertility trends were just as would be expected. Welfare policy may not
explain all of the rise and fall of modern fertility but it explains a
whole lot more than the standard modernisation model.
The collapse of European fertility rates shows the force of present-day
welfare state pressures. Whether the European trends can be reversed is
entirely unknown. In English-speaking societies the prospects are a little
better but far from bright. Australia has not yet reached the 1.5
benchmark. Nevertheless, Paul Kelly’s conclusion is apt: "A
population policy for Australia should recognise that having children
constitutes a social good different from buying a new car and should be
sustained by a new social contract. The core aims of such a policy should
be to reverse the fertility decline, to devise a strategy of long-term
population growth and to support women in integrating family and
job."
Kelly’s "new social contract" is not exactly new: it is the
old post-war contract renewed, and modified only to incorporate women’s
employment. Desirable though such a policy is, it is deeply counter to the
ideals of today’s welfare state. How can families and children be
supported without reversing the flow of upwards redistribution? And what
sort of political leadership is there that will negotiate such a
re-redistribution?