Like what you've read?

On Line Opinion is the only Australian site where you get all sides of the story. We don't
charge, but we need your support. Here�s how you can help.

  • Advertise

    We have a monthly audience of 70,000 and advertising packages from $200 a month.

  • Volunteer

    We always need commissioning editors and sub-editors.

  • Contribute

    Got something to say? Submit an essay.


 The National Forum   Donate   Your Account   On Line Opinion   Forum   Blogs   Polling   About   
On Line Opinion logo ON LINE OPINION - Australia's e-journal of social and political debate

Subscribe!
Subscribe





On Line Opinion is a not-for-profit publication and relies on the generosity of its sponsors, editors and contributors. If you would like to help, contact us.
___________

Syndicate
RSS/XML


RSS 2.0

Targeting the yuan: a feel-good but futile response

By Derek Scissors - posted Thursday, 16 September 2010


The likelihood of congressional action targeting China for pegging its currency to the dollar is increasing at an alarming rate. The precise form of legislation is not yet clear, and some possible outcomes are better than others for the American economy. But the core claim is the same: the Chinese yuan is sharply undervalued against the dollar, undervaluation is a major factor in the bilateral trade deficit, it costs the US millions of jobs, and punishing China for the value of its currency will solve all.

This ostensible logic fails at every step. The extent of the yuan’s misalignment is unclear, and so designing real remedies is almost impossible. More importantly, undervaluation is not a major factor in the bilateral deficit and not a factor at all in the overall trade deficit. And there is very little evidence that the yuan’s undervaluation costs the US a large number of jobs. China is often a poor economic partner, but retaliation aimed at the exchange rate will not fix anything.

Cannot quantify the undervaluation

At this point, the legislative focus is on classifying an undervalued currency as an illegal subsidy and permitting protection against that supposed subsidy in the form of countervailing duties (CVD) or something similar. The immediate problem with such a proposal is that even the loudest proponents of CVD cannot determine the exact amount of undervaluation of the yuan and therefore cannot properly set the size of CVD in this case.

Advertisement

Protectionists typically use phrases like “as much as 50 per cent undervalued”. This is understandable, because China is a non-market economy suffering a slew of state-imposed distortions, making it very difficult to determine the correct level for the exchange rate. However, this level of imprecision is not useful in responsible trade policy.

Typical ranges for undervaluation from institutions such as the International Monetary Fund are 5-30 per cent, which is also unhelpful. Moreover, the extent of undervaluation changes each month - will the duties applied be changed each month?

Will not cut the bilateral deficit

Even if CVD or an equivalent mechanism could be properly constructed - and done so without harming America’s other trade partners or triggering major World Trade Organization decisions against the US - these measures will do little to reduce the bilateral trade deficit. There are simple and more complex reasons for this but, both point to the same conclusion.

The simple reason is that the American economy is much bigger than the Chinese economy, and US policies therefore matter much more to the trade deficit than do Chinese policies. The more complex reason is that trade balances are a direct reflection of national consumption and saving. The US runs a trade deficit with the rest of the world because Americans consume more than they save and the rest of the world saves more than it consumes. The level of the exchange rate bears only indirectly on savings and consumption, so it has little effect on the trade deficit needle.

Both arguments lead to the same conclusion: by far the most effective method of reducing the trade deficit is for the US to save more. And the American people have saved more in the past two years. The main reason the trade deficit has barely budged is that the federal government has countered the increase in American private saving by spending over $2.5 trillion it did not have. This is not the only factor behind the continued bilateral trade deficit, but it is easily the most important.

Will not create jobs

Even if the exchange rate mattered a great deal to the bilateral deficit, a lower bilateral deficit would not actually lead to a lower total American trade deficit. If CVD or other American trade measures did make Chinese exports to the US prohibitively costly, production of those goods would not shift to the US.

Advertisement

Instead, it would shift to other low-cost areas, such as Vietnam or Bangladesh. Applying duties to Chinese goods would not suddenly make the American textile, toy, furniture, or even computer-assembly industries globally competitive, and these are the primary imports from the PRC. Globalisation means the US can punish China, but it cannot simply turn Chinese losses into American gains.

Finally, even if retaliating against Beijing for pegging the yuan to the dollar somehow did noticeably cut into the aggregate US trade deficit, there is little reason to believe this would create more and better American jobs. The idea that a smaller trade deficit means more American jobs is simplistic to the point of being useless. The US trade deficit peaked in 2006, when unemployment was 4.6 per cent. By 2009, the deficit in goods and services had fallen by half from 2006, yet the unemployment rate had doubled.

The reason is the consumption orientation of the American economy. When consumption is strong, growth is high and jobs are created. Because strong consumption leads to a trade deficit, high growth and low unemployment occur in times when the trade deficit is sizable. In terms of quality, the jobs American demand creates in China are in clothing, toys, and assembly operations. It is not obvious that these positions are superior to the port handling, distribution, and retailing jobs involved in importing these goods.

Change the focus

The PRC’s trade behaviour makes it a tempting target. The June announcement of an end to the dollar peg was fraudulent, and the exchange rate is only one part of China’s non-cooperative policy. Beijing is now taking important action to liberalise its balance-of-payments regime, which is necessary before the dollar peg can genuinely be broken, but the process has begun late and will be slow.

Nonetheless, congressional action targeting the peg will not work. The level of CVD, for example, cannot be set properly. The exchange rate is not a major factor in the trade deficit. A successful effort to push production out of the PRC would only move it to other low-cost sites. And it is not at all clear that a smaller trade deficit would translate to more and better American jobs. More fruitful policy steps are:

  • cutting the federal budget deficit by cutting spending, thereby giving a boost to net US saving and putting a real dent in the trade deficit;
  • making Chinese balance-of-payments liberalisation the primary American goal in bilateral economic relations, for example in the Strategic and Economic Dialogue; and
  • rather than taking stabs at the extent of exchange rate undervaluation, the Departments of Treasury and Commerce should estimate the extent of subsidies for state-owned enterprises, another tough task but a much bigger harm to American firms.

Feel-good policy

Legislation targeting the yuan may feel good, but it will not accomplish anything.

  1. Pages:
  2. 1
  3. 2
  4. All

First published by the Heritage Foundation on September 9, 2010.



Discuss in our Forums

See what other readers are saying about this article!

Click here to read & post comments.

Share this:
reddit this reddit thisbookmark with del.icio.us Del.icio.usdigg thisseed newsvineSeed NewsvineStumbleUpon StumbleUponsubmit to propellerkwoff it

About the Author

Derek Scissors, PhD, is Research Fellow in Asia Economic Policy in the Asian Studies Center at The Heritage Foundation in the United States.

Other articles by this Author

All articles by Derek Scissors

Creative Commons LicenseThis work is licensed under a Creative Commons License.

Article Tools
Comment Comments
Print Printable version
Subscribe Subscribe
Email Email a friend
Advertisement

About Us Search Discuss Feedback Legals Privacy