Like what you've read?

On Line Opinion is the only Australian site where you get all sides of the story. We don't
charge, but we need your support. Here�s how you can help.

  • Advertise

    We have a monthly audience of 70,000 and advertising packages from $200 a month.

  • Volunteer

    We always need commissioning editors and sub-editors.

  • Contribute

    Got something to say? Submit an essay.


 The National Forum   Donate   Your Account   On Line Opinion   Forum   Blogs   Polling   About   
On Line Opinion logo ON LINE OPINION - Australia's e-journal of social and political debate

Subscribe!
Subscribe





On Line Opinion is a not-for-profit publication and relies on the generosity of its sponsors, editors and contributors. If you would like to help, contact us.
___________

Syndicate
RSS/XML


RSS 2.0

Fiscal stimulus: handouts v cuts

By Saul Eslake - posted Tuesday, 3 March 2009


This is probably the most attractive design feature of the government’s proposals. It avoids the problem of the stimulus continuing after it has ceased to be necessary - and thus adding to upward pressure on interest rates once a recovery is eventually under way - which has been a failing of previous attempts to use fiscal policy to counter the effects of recession.

Ideally, any suggested changes to the government’s proposals which would entail permanent reductions in revenue or increases in spending - such as an increase in Newstart Allowances or other payments to the unemployed, for which there is an arguable case - should be funded, at least after the present downturn has passed, by reductions in other areas of government spending or by an increase in taxes.

The government’s proposals don’t stack up quite as well against the “targeted” criterion:

Advertisement
  • the government does seem to be unduly focused on timing major cash handouts so as to minimise the likelihood of consecutive quarters of negative real GDP growth and hence what media commentators, much more so than economists, refer to as a “technical recession” (I have described this elsewhere as the “Technical Recession Avoidance Program” or TRAP). The current set of proposals may well succeed in this aim, but to me the objective seems rather spurious;
  • the $12.4 billion cash grants component of the current proposal is less tightly targeted to those most likely to spend it than the previous (Economic Security Strategy) package. Some of it will go to quite affluent households (including to second income earners in such households) who are more likely to save it than spend it;
  • while I don’t doubt that the $28 billion of infrastructure spending will directly boost aggregate demand and employment in a timely manner, a different emphasis within this component could perhaps have produced greater long-term gains for an equivalent amount of spending; and
  • it’s not clear, for example, that giving every school in the country the opportunity to upgrade or acquire halls, laboratories, and libraries (though there are undoubtedly many which are sorely needed) provides the best means of boosting productivity over the long term, or of addressing other long-term challenges such as climate change or altering patterns of water use.

Perhaps the argument in favour of “small-scale” proposals such as those which make up the bulk of the infrastructure component is that they can be done quickly - for example there is a trade-off between “targeting” and “timely” - and that economic infrastructure objectives will be dealt with in a separate package. However to the extent that the latter is the case, this may have some bearing on judgments about the appropriate size of this particular package.

I conclude with some observations on the impact of the government’s proposals on the condition of Australia’s public finances.

The budget deficits envisaged in the Updated Economic and Fiscal Outlook (UEFO) are not excessive by historical or international standards. UEFO forecasts the budget deficit to peak at 2.9 per cent of GDP in 2009-10, compared with peaks during previous recessions of 4.1 per cent in 1992-93 and 3.3 per cent in 1984-85. This is with the OECD’s most recent forecast of OECD area budget deficits peaking at 4.1 per cent of GDP in 2010 (a forecast which does not include the stimulus now close to being enacted in the United States).

The budget deficit may well end up being larger than currently projected if the additional fiscal measures are brought forward or if the economy fares worse than currently forecast; but there is room for that without exceeding previous peaks. And, history (which on this point is conveniently summarised in a recent paper (by Carmen Reinhart and Ken Rogoff)) suggests that the ultimate fiscal cost of episodes such as the present one ends up being considerably greater if appropriate ameliorative action is delayed.

Likewise, the levels of public debt projected in the UEFO are not excessive or alarming by either historical or international standards. UEFO forecasts that net public debt will reach 5.2 per cent of GDP by the end of June 2012. Again, it could easily be more than that, especially if the $200 billion borrowing limit envisaged in legislation presented to the Parliament is fully utilised. But the UEFO projection compares with the previous peak of 18.5 per cent of GDP in 1995-96, and with OECD forecasts of net government debt of 48 per cent of GDP for the OECD area as a whole (a forecast which is also likely to be an underestimate).

Advertisement

It is of course true that the debt envisaged in the UEFO forecasts will need to be serviced and (perhaps) eventually paid off; and that the scope for doing so through asset sales is considerably less than was the case with the previous peak level of public debt.

It may well be that servicing or repaying the debt incurred now will ultimately require higher taxes. That would be, in many ways, regrettable; but it may also reflect the fact that the tax cuts implemented in the middle years of this decade were only sustainable to the extent that the commodities boom which largely paid for them continued (which it hasn’t). I would also argue that a modest increase in debt now and (if necessary) taxes later is preferable to much larger increases in debt and taxes (to say nothing of other policies that could be characterised frankly as bad) which might eventually prove unavoidable if the economic downturn were to become much worse as a result of policy inertia.

  1. Pages:
  2. 1
  3. Page 2
  4. All


Discuss in our Forums

See what other readers are saying about this article!

Click here to read & post comments.

9 posts so far.

Share this:
reddit this reddit thisbookmark with del.icio.us Del.icio.usdigg thisseed newsvineSeed NewsvineStumbleUpon StumbleUponsubmit to propellerkwoff it

About the Author

Saul Eslake is a Vice-Chancellor’s Fellow at the University of Tasmania.

Other articles by this Author

All articles by Saul Eslake

Creative Commons LicenseThis work is licensed under a Creative Commons License.

Photo of Saul Eslake
Article Tools
Comment 9 comments
Print Printable version
Subscribe Subscribe
Email Email a friend
Advertisement

About Us Search Discuss Feedback Legals Privacy