Historically, we know that a boom - embodying excessive asset-price inflation - is followed by a bust - a sharp decline in asset prices. It happened with the
tulip boom, with the South Sea Bubble, with a whole series of stockmarket booms, including the one that
led to the Great Crash of 1929, and with innumerable housing/real-estate booms in Australia and many other countries. The certainty that asset-price inflation
will be followed by asset-price collapse may not be quite as sure as death and taxes but, historically, it appears to belong in much the same league.
So we know that the present housing boom in Australia will - almost certainly - be followed by a housing bust.
After that bust, the smart league - including most of the banks - will soldier on with their pockets stuffed but many, especially in the middle-income and poorer
brigade, will be in thrall to the banks through crippling mortgage payments for years to come. If they can hang on long enough, they might get their money back
when the next boom comes. Hope springs eternal ...
Advertisement
So the question is not so much whether we'll have a bust but when it will
come, how long it will last and how distressing to how many people it will be.
The deeper question too is how savagely it will affect the entire economy
- fixed-capital investment, public and private spending, the trade and payments
balance.
At this late point in the boom, there is very little prospect that the bust
can be avoided or even that it can be substantially moderated.
The only effective way of avoiding a bust is to avoid or manage the boom that
otherwise would inevitably precipitate it.
To discover how this can be done, we need no exotic theories or obscure precedents.
We need only to go back 30 to 60 years or so and reflect on our own experience
towards the end of World War Two and in the quarter century afterwards.
At that time, two crucial policy instruments determined our economic and social
destiny. They were the commitment to full employment embodied in the White
Paper on Full Employment of 1945 and the Banking Act of 1944.
The commitment to full employment gave us stable rates of economic growth
and social welfare that did not rule out booms and busts of whatever kind but
did ensure that all our human resources - or most of them - could and would be
used to meet the variety of needs of our society at low to negligible rates of
inflation.
Advertisement
We cannot be sure by what percentage a given rate of unemployment reduces
our gross domestic product. We cannot be sure that a 10 per cent jobless rate
will cut a GDP of, say, $500 billion to $450 billion but we can be sure that the
cut in available resources to meet the needs of the community will be substantial
- and that the need to divert resources to support the unemployed will dilute
supply to meet capital and consumer demand.
Let me add too that the past 30 years have shown how hard it is to get back
real growth and real investment - to retrieve industry that has been lost and
jobs that have migrated - once they have been lost.
The end of World War Two was a period of acute housing shortage, accentuated
by an influx of migrants just about as large as, if not larger than at any time
in our previous history.
However, there was no housing boom - no asset-price inflation in housing of
the kind that has afflicted the Australian society and economy in more recent
years.
That was partly because our labour force was fully employed; but then and
later it was also due to the way in which the banking system, under the Banking
Act of 1944, was managed to meet the balanced needs of the economy and the society.
Here we cannot examine all the elements of the Banking Act of 1944 and the
White Paper on Full Employment but some elements were crucial. They were
-
- Full employment should be the government's top priority;
- Interest rates should be kept low;
- The government, through the central bank, should direct credit so that it
should be available in a balanced way - neither too much nor too little - to all
areas of the economy and society.
The Commonwealth Bank and later the Reserve Bank, acting as Australia's central
bank, could and did use its power to discipline and its influence to guide the
commercial banks in their lending and their behaviour generally. It could withdraw
funds into Special Accounts or, in the ultimate, it could de-licence. More regularly
and effectively, it issued "guidance" to the banks on increasing their
lending to factories or farmers; or reducing their lending for stockmarket investment
or real estate.
It may fairly be claimed that, in a free economy, banks should be allowed
to operate freely, with a minimum of regulation. However, that minimum of regulation
is vital. Without it, the banks' tendency is to indulge in more and more licentious
behaviour in the pursuit of profit and market share, and to neglect the broader
welfare of the economy and society from which they derive their resources, their
privileges and their power - and which, in the end, they are or should be duty-bound
to serve.
The experience of the last quarter century in Australia has again demonstrated
this powerful tendency to indulge in licentious behaviour and emphasised the need
to regulate that behaviour by the community they are privileged - and duty-bound
- to serve.
The financial system is now more complex than it was in 1970. Funds available
to the banks, either directly or through subsidiaries, are massive compared with
a generation ago. Pension funds are both enormous and place the destiny of millions
of Australians more completely in the hands of the banks and associated financial
institutions than ever before.
Effectively, therefore, we have a choice between responsible regulation of
the banking system or increasing instability and possible catastrophic collapse
of our financial system, with consequent damage to our whole society and political
system. Without responsible regulation of the banking system, we risk another
Great Depression - but one that could be deeper and more devastating than the
one which only the most elderly among us now remember.
That brings us back to the present housing boom and the way in which it might
be managed. In the past 30 years or so, "management" has simply been
to raise interest rates and so kill the boom and much in the whole economy besides.
Whole armies of jobless have been created, factories have been closed, farms lost,
bankruptcies precipitated, fixed-capital private and public investment severely
cut. That is the worst way to deal with a housing or any other boom - a boom whose
inevitable collapse can be foreseen with the clarity indicated above and against
which any responsible managers of our financial and economic system must institute
safeguards.
What we must do is move away from the excessive free-market approach of the
last 30 years - especially the period since the deregulation of the banks in the
1980s - and back to the essence of the regulation of the banking system that we
had in the period from 1944 to 1970, a period that was also marked, as we have
noted, by a dedicated commitment to policies of full employment.
In the more complex financial world of today, regulation will now differ in
some and probably much of the detail from that of the earlier period but its core
character should remain the same. In the matter of housing, legislation should
permit the government, either directly or through the central bank, to issue guidance
as soon as danger of overheating of the market threatens and signs of asset-price
inflation occur. Under such management, the flow of mortgage credit would be restrained,
the price of housing for the younger and poorer sectors of the population would
be kept down and finance for other sectors of the economy would be more readily
available and, we might assume, the guidance from the government would encourage
the flow of funds into these other productive sectors.
These are fundamental issues and our current problems with housing - and real
estate more generally - especially in the last twenty years, illustrate how wrong
and how damaging our financial and economic policies have been. (Although it is
a subject for more detailed analysis, I must note here that homelessness in Australia
is, at present, a national disgrace. If we are to regard ourselves as a fair and
compassionate society, we must revise our economic, financial and social policies
to ensure that every man, woman and child in this country has a decent place to
live.)
Consequently, our approach to resolving the boom-and-bust housing syndrome
should be - and indeed must be - part of a broadranging re-appraisal of our financial
and economic policies and the institution of measures which will give us more
stable growth and more secure and equitable living levels for all our people,
rich and poor, young and old - for traditional families and single parents alike
and especially for our children. We should not tolerate thousands of homeless
children while bank boards hand out obscene salary packages of millions of dollars
to their CEOs or tens of millions to their crony bankers as "Golden Handshakes"
when they retire.
Sadly, there are few signs at the moment that our policymakers are about to make
this reappraisal or adopt the more enlightened approaches that will pilot us into
safer waters.