Whether one looks at protectionist policies of Europe and America or
the free-market approach of Australia, rural sectors are in decline in
mature economies. Orthodox economic theory appears unable to provide an
analytical framework that can explain this phenomenon in the real world of
mature growing economies.
For almost three decades Australia has pursued ad hoc rural policy
underwritten by market economic theory advocating increased efficiency,
rising productivity, and free international trade. The legacy of this
policy approach is a battered and debilitated rural sector characterised
by industry crises, volatile commodity prices, inadequate farm incomes,
declining services, rising levels of poverty, suicide rates of
international significance and population relocation.
To throw some light on how rural Australia has arrived at this sorry
situation, we should eschew the rhetoric and do a reality check by shining
the statistical spotlight on farm incomes; tracing rural policy
development since the 1980s and examining an alternative analytical
framework while recognising the reality of political economics. We might
then be in a position to say what needs to be done for regional
development.
Advertisement
Farm Incomes
The current improvement in cattle and wool prices is being heralded by
the metropolitan media as evidence of a booming rural sector and the
success of free-market policies. Analysis of purchasing power discloses
that in terms of national income distribution, rural Australia is not
booming. Indeed, real income of broadacre agriculture has markedly
declined over time.
If one examines rural industry terms of trade (using figures from ABARE),
the real net value of farm production and the consumer price index over
the period from 1978 to 2001, it becomes obvious that farmers' terms of
trade have declined markedly while prices in the wider community have
risen i.e. prices for farm production have risen more slowly than prices
measured by the CPI.
Looking at the relationship between costs, production, debt and nominal
farm income for the same period, it can be deduced that costs drive
production that is debt financed. Also demonstrated is that policy
directed to increasing efficiency and rising productivity has made little
difference to the value of farm income that remains in farm hands. The
increasing divergence between gross value of farm production (GVFP) and
net value of farm production (NVFP) confirms the rising proportion of farm
production that is being redistributed to the wider community. In other
words, policy directed to rising efficiency and increased productivity has
not improved the relationship between GVFP and NVFP.
The policy response under market economics has been to reduce the
number of farmers. This way NVFP is shared among fewer and fewer farmers.
Mathematically, average farm income should rise. An alternative
interpretation is that the increasing divergence between GVFP and NVFP
represents discretionary policy redistributing income from the farm sector
to underwrite incomes and living standards in the wider community.
Rural Policy
In 1994 Jonathan P. Sher and Katrina Rowe Sher published a paper in the
Journal of Research in Rural Education. It was based upon work they had
been commissioned to undertake for the Australian DPIE and was not so much
an economic analysis as a narrative outlining their findings and
conclusions drawn from wide international experience.
Sher and Sher had been asked to prepare a paper outlining a strategy
for rural development based upon rural education and entrepreneurship.
When they began to review existing Australian literature on the subject,
they were astounded to find that very little was available. They found
detailed material on specific rural places, rural groups and individual
industries but they could not source a single convincing contribution that
addressed the reality of life beyond cities and suburbs. They came to the
conclusion that in 1993 for Australia, there existed no rural development
strategy at all.
Advertisement
They changed their original task from rural education and
entrepreneurship to one of writing a program for rural development. They
used their experiences from OECD work and observations of applied
empowerment strategies to compile their contribution to Australian rural
development policy.
What is clear from their paper is that the Australian agro-political
movement and major political parties enthusiastically embraced market
theory from the early 1980s without a substantive rural development plan
or understanding of likely outcomes. It appears ideology was the driving
force.
According to Sher and Sher, empowerment should not be understood as a
policy option in which government has no role. Empowerment of communities
is based upon some central concepts - all involved parties agree on some
important fundamentals and an operational strategy; each stakeholder must
be empowered to contribute specific skills and the activity must be
appropriately funded. It would be necessary for government to develop
empowerment-promoting policies and accept a role as a partner in rural
development.
Over the past three to five years, however, constructive discussion on
rural policy appears to have waned and, in the name of empowering rural
communities, politicians have effectively fragmented the rural voice and
managed dissent by arguing that rural communities know best their own
solutions.
The policy position that local communities are responsible for their
own destiny carries a number of interesting implications. It would appear
that rural policy accepts responsibility only for positive economic
outcomes such as deregulated labour markets, competitive exchange rate,
low inflation and interest rates, vibrant industries and communities that
are growing. Negative economic outcomes affecting industries, communities
and regions are not the consequence of policy. They are stand-alone
situations determined somehow within communities lacking a sense of
"community" and quality local or industry leadership.
Shifting responsibility for perverse policy outcomes back to community
level makes individual communities feel somehow to blame for their plight.
Consequently, every small community seeks to demonstrate responsibility
for its situation by chasing individual solutions such as local tourism,
retirement housing; local market days, and some promising industry.
Effectively, each community competes against its neighbor to secure its
own small portion of any available project or dollar.
This is an 'enclave theory' of rural renewal based upon a philosophical
position.
The1999 Draft Report of the Productivity Commission tells us that the
majority of small rural communities continue to grow. Overall, rural
population is growing in absolute numbers - but the distribution is
shifting, producing such phenomena as sponge cities and coastal drift.
Population is declining in the 31 per cent of inland communities based
upon grazing, wheat and mining. These towns comprise the service centres
for major industries in inland rural Australia and herein lies the policy
problem.
Graphical analysis of the monetary value of all farm assistance
expressed as a percentage of farm gate revenue (%PSE) in OECD countries
from 1997 to 1999 reveals that all member countries except Australia and
NZ increased the %PSE. (Australia continued to reduce support from 7 per
cnet to 6 per cent while NZ remained constant at 2 per cent). This
suggests that OECD member nations considered farm revenue support a more
important policy mechanism than empowerment.
Alternative Analytical Framework
Engel's Law states that as income grows, the demand for food grows
less than proportionately. This is a Law of pervasive importance in
economic growth. - Kindleberger
Its presence can be demonstrated whether considering the behavior of an
individual, a nation or several nations, and it explains why as an economy
grows and incomes increase, demand increasingly shifts away from food with
low-income elasticities of demand e.g. grain and other staple foods.
Consequently, the relative price of food declines compared to expenditure
on manufactured goods and services. These effects of Engel's Law occur
across both domestic and internationally traded goods and services.
In the real world, Engel's Law can help explain the structural
realignment of agricultural sectors in economies as they grow over time.
An important point is that Engel's Law does not disappear at some given
level of economic maturity. It is a continuous process and mature
economies such as Europe, America and Australia continue to experience
ongoing structural realignment of agricultural sectors in their economies.
It is important to remember that while agriculture declines relatively
in an economy, in absolute terms agricultural output continues to grow.
Engel's Law directly challenges market economics and its belief in an
international free-trade solution and establishes the case for managed
trade. The political agenda that restricts Australian trade-policy debate
to a position of either 'fortress Australia' or 'free trade' says more
about the quality of politicians and ideology than about the breadth of
economic theory.
Conventional supply -and-demand theory explains price determination
under market forces through business-cycle activity. There is an optimum
price level determined in the market when the level of supply equals the
level of demand. From the price elasticity of demand for food implied in
Engel's Law, it follows that production beyond the optimum level will see
prices decline disproportionately to the increase in output.
Considered together, Engel's Law and conventional supply-and-demand
theory mean that rural decline is a problem of structural realignment of a
rural sector in a growing mature economy. Engel's law explains why under
rising incomes food expenditure falls proportionately in overall
expenditure patterns. Structurally, this implies rural production will
decline as a proportion of overall aggregate output in a mature economy.
Supply-and-demand theory explains the volatility of the price over a
trade/business cycle. Supply and demand theory also explains the
oscillations of the terms-of-trade curve around the long-term trend curve
at any given moment in time
Market economic theory with its emphasis upon increased efficiency and
rising productivity cannot solve the long-term decline in real farm
prices. Continued adherence to market theory is more likely to reinforce
trade-cycle momentum than produce desired stability. Indeed, in time of
international oversupply, increasing efficiency and rising productivity
will have the perverse policy effect of exacerbating the oversupply
problem and exert increasing downward pressure upon already inadequate
prices.
The solution lies in management of structural realignment and not in
increasing production.
Political Economics
Political economics would identify the Australian economy as a
competitive capitalist system. All the major political parties easily meet
the characteristics of contemporary conservatism. They all philosophically
support low taxation, small government, free international trade,
competition policy in some form and 'empowerment of rural communities'
regional development strategies.
Party policy positions differ only in degree and rhetoric. In other
words, their political orders are remarkably similar while their economic
orders differ only at the margins.
Specific policy issues of rural income distribution, drought policies and
regional development comply with the central tenets of contemporary
conservatism and competitive capitalism.
The Universal Solution: Regional Development
The Productivity Commission Draft Report (May 1999) identified rural
towns in decline as primarily support-centers for dryland grazing, wheat
and mining industries. These major rural industries comprise broadacre
agriculture accounting for approximately 60 per cent of gross value of
agricultural output. In these towns, protracted commodity price
dislocation and volatility has undermined income stability, saving,
investment, industry confidence, regional development and stability.
Recently, commodity prices have recovered somewhat but, over time,
purchasing power of commodity prices remains below real price movements in
the wider community. Given the cyclical nature of commodity prices, it is
uncertain how long the current relief will remain
Rural and regional development through infrastructure expenditure has
become the solution slogan for politicians and market economists to
address these underlying rural problems. Rural and regional development,
however, implies establishment of new industries to rebuild declining
towns or regions. Infrastructure by itself is only one aspect of the
underlying problem.
Moreover, to attract industries to new locations, certain
characteristics are required - a core population base necessary to deliver
services, capacity to service markets and a skilled workforce. Competitive
business does not welcome unnecessary hardships when selecting a new
location. It is more likely to select towns offering established service
centers and required work skills.
The rural workforce is poorly educated relative to urban workers where
15 per cent of breadwinners hold a university degree at pass or higher
level compared to 8 per cent in rural areas (Productivity Commission Draft
Report). Moreover, and according to the National Farmers' Federation, only
25 per cent of Australia's farm workforce have completed secondary school
or hold a trade or tertiary qualification. The figure for New Zealand is
50 per cent and Europe 90 per cent.
Real-world industries looking to relocate are more likely to seek out
vibrant and viable towns possessing the necessary attributes. While it is
fine to include tourism and retirement industries in a balanced
development program, over reliance on these low-income industries could
prove self-defeating. Low-income, aged communities characterised by
entrenched poverty traps are unlikely to attract modern expanding
industries. Older type industries seeking low-wage workers to survive will
transfer their own problems to debilitated towns.
What Needs to be Done
Economics is about choice - and market economics concentrating on
efficiency and microeconomic reform is only one option. Solutions are
available but they lie beyond narrow market theories and embrace income
distribution, sustainable economic growth, full employment, rising
standards of living and equality of opportunity. Solutions must be
two-tiered: short term and long term. And the overall policy objective of
rural and regional development must be broken into two major economic
targets: stemming the disproportionate flow of GVFP to the wider
community; and reality-based regional development for declining broadacre
service towns
Development of a comprehensive regional development strategy will
require a "sea change" from the popular empowerment thesis.
Political economics tells us that no directional change in rural policy
will be possible without change in the established Australian political
and economic orders. This will require a strong rural voice in the
political process and the development of a third way for Australia, lying
somewhere between competitive capitalism and over-zealous modern
liberalism. Without a directional change in rural policy, substantive
rural renewal will not take place. Established commodity price volatility
will continue to undermine income stability, saving and investment
patterns, industry confidence and regional stability and development.
This is an edited version of a larger paper, available from the New Country Party website.