This is part 2 of George Soros's article. Part
one is here.
Market fundamentalism is a false and dangerous ideology. It is false on
at least two counts. First, it profoundly misapprehends the way financial
markets operate. It assumes that markets tend toward equilibrium and that
equilibrium assures the optimum allocation of resources. Academic
economists have proceeded far beyond general equilibrium - multiple
equilibriums are all the rage now - but market fundamentalists continue to
believe they have solid science behind them, not just economics but also
Charles Darwin's theory of survival of the fittest. Second, by equating
private interests with the public interest, market fundamentalism endows
the pursuit of self-interest with a moral quality.
But if financial markets do not tend toward equilibrium, as the theory
of reflexivity maintains, private interests cannot be equated with the
public interest. Left to their own devices, financial markets are liable
to go to socially disruptive extremes.
Advertisement
The fallacy of endowing the market mechanism with a moral quality goes
deeper still. What distinguishes markets is exactly that they are amoral--that
is to say, moral considerations do not find expression in market prices.
That is because efficient markets by definition have so many participants
that no single one can affect the market price. Even if some participants
are held back by moral scruples, others will take their place at only
marginally different prices. For instance, moralists cannot prevent
alcohol and tobacco companies from raising capital on more or less the
same terms as not-so-sinful enterprises. As a consequence, anonymous
market participants need not be overly concerned with the social
consequences of their actions because those consequences are so marginal.
The amorality of financial markets is one of the factors that contribute
to their efficiency: It allows participants to be single-minded about
maximizing their returns without regard to the social consequences. (Of
course the concept of efficient markets is only an abstraction. In reality
many large participants are not anonymous and their decisions may sway
others.) It is exactly because markets are amoral that we cannot leave the
allocation of resources entirely to them. Society cannot hold together
without some consideration of the common interest. If private interests
cannot be equated with the public interest, the public interest must be
given expression in some other way than through the market.
Here we must draw a distinction between rulemaking and playing by the
rules. As market participants, we may pursue our self-interest as long as
we play by the rules. But as rulemakers we must be guided by the common
interest--and in a democracy we are all rulemakers. By claiming that the
public interest is best served by allowing people to pursue their
self-interest, market fundamentalists have erased the distinction. Those
who subscribe to this convenient ideology have no compunction about
bending the rules to their own advantage. The result is not perfect
competition but crony capitalism, where the rich and powerful feel morally
justified in enjoying their privileged position.
The dangers of market fundamentalism are particularly evident in the
international arena. The development of our international financial
institutions has not kept pace with the growth of global financial
markets. As a result we have seen several major international financial
crises since 1980. Their impact on our economy has been relatively modest
because whenever a crisis threatened our prosperity the Federal Reserve
intervened aggressively--as with the Long Term Capital Management crisis
in 1998. But many other countries--Argentina, Brazil, Mexico, Thailand,
Indonesia, Korea, Russia--have been devastated, some more than once.
Instead of recognizing that financial markets are inherently unstable and
bigger markets require stronger public institutions to maintain stability,
market fundamentalists have reached the opposite conclusion: They blame
the International Monetary Fund (IMF) for the instability. They claim that
the IMF rescue packages have created a "moral hazard" by
encouraging markets to extend more credit than they would have otherwise.
Yielding to market-fundamentalist pressure, the IMF has reversed its
policy from bailouts to "bail-ins"--in which the private sector
must make concessions as well. Since investment banks are not motivated by
charity, they want to be paid for their part of the bail-in burden--which
means higher interests, which further undermines a developing country's
economic growth.
The change in IMF policy in the aftermath of the emerging-market crisis
of 1997 to 1999 has increased the cost of capital going to debtor
countries. As a result, recent years have seen a reverse flow of capital
from the periphery to the center as demonstrated by America's
ever-increasing current account deficit, which now exceeds $400 billion or
4 percent of GDP. This has the makings of another bubble that must
eventually burst, although the timing cannot be predicted. The recent
weakening of the dollar is an ominous sign, especially as the main
alternatives--the euro and the yen--are not particularly attractive. The
financial crisis in Brazil is even more threatening. From the
market-fundamentalist perspective, Brazil has done everything right; yet
its bonds today yield more than 20 percent in dollar terms, and no country
can live with such high interest rates. After the Bush administration
reversed its previous opposition, the IMF recently put together a large,
$30 billion bailout package, but the markets were not impressed. Having
been told about moral hazard and private-sector burden-sharing, they are
determined to avoid it. After a brief rally, yields settled back at more
than 20 percent. By imposing such high interest rates, financial markets
are engaging in a self-fulfilling prophecy that is making Brazil
insolvent. If Brazil fails, the international financial system as
currently constituted has failed. Global financial markets have created an
uneven playing field that cannot be sustained in its present form.
There is an urgent need to reform the system by strengthening the IMF's
function as lender of last resort to countries that cannot get
private-sector credit and by encouraging developing countries to pursue
more domestic-led growth, which will lessen their dependence on U.S.-led
growth. This will require far-reaching institutional changes, but there is
no sign that the Bush administration and others in economic authority
recognize the need--partly because they remain beholden to
market-fundamentalist thinking.
In the international arena, as in the domestic, market fundamentalism
assumes that the collective pursuit of private interest produces economic
stability. But as today's turmoil shows, the lack of ethical principles
and social concerns--whether among governments or accountants--creates
enormous instability. Values are shaped by exactly the same
reflexive process as market prices. As I explained earlier, there is a
two-way connection between values and economic fundamentals (the economic
performance of companies and governments) on the one hand and market
prices on the other. There is the "normal" connection studied in
economic theory by which the supply and demand curves determine prices;
there is also an inverse, reflexive connection by which market
developments have repercussions on the participants' values and the
so-called fundamentals. The more susceptible the participants' values are
to market developments, the more unstable the system becomes. Firmly held
ethical, professional, and social principles serve as an anchor, keeping
financial markets stable. Conditions then approximate those stipulated by
economic theory: The values are more or less independent of markets, and
the outcome is a more or less stable equilibrium. But when people pursue
financial success without regard for other considerations, they become
willing participants in initially self-reinforcing but eventually
self-defeating processes.
Advertisement
This is exactly what has happened in the recent boom/bust cycle. Warren
Buffett and a few others refused to be swayed by the irrational exuberance
of the '90s and continued to base their decisions on the fundamentals of
economic performance. But the vast majority of investors were swept away
by a self-reinforcing tide, and many people who had never previously
invested in stocks got sucked in. The removal of restrictions stimulated
entrepreneurial and inventive talents; shareholders' interests took
precedence over other considerations. The exuberance was not entirely
irrational. Only when the fundamentals could not keep up with the
expectations did the process become unsustainable. That is when ethical
and professional principles failed to keep the process within bounds.
The argument about stability is relevant not only to financial markets
but to society at large. As we have seen, financial markets are amoral,
whereas society cannot remain stable without some shared values. Although
amorality renders financial markets efficient, it also renders them
inhuman. Some sense of humanity must be introduced through the political
process--even if it means sacrificing some efficiency, as measured in GDP.
That is the fundamental insight that American politics has been missing.
Market fundamentalists have managed to convince themselves and others that
the proper objective of policy is to protect markets from regulation in
the interests of efficiency and economic growth. They point to the failure
of socialism in all its forms. But this argument is based on faulty logic.
It does not follow from the fact that regulations are imperfect that
unregulated markets are perfect. The fact is, all human constructs,
including markets, are imperfect in one way or another; perfection is
beyond our reach. That is where fundamentalist beliefs, including market
fundamentalism, are always wrong: They lay claim to ultimate truth.
To be sure, in developing a new regulatory framework we must remember
that regulations are liable to be even more imperfect than markets. They
need a feedback mechanism that allows mistakes to be corrected. That is
what makes regulated markets superior to central planning. In the absence
of feedback either from markets or from free speech and free elections,
there is no limit to how far governments can go wrong. But democracy can
keep the excesses of government within bounds, just as government can
contain the excesses of the financial markets.
In the last two decades or so--and particularly since the '90s--we have
given financial markets too much free rein. We have allowed corporations
to maximize profits to the detriment of considerations like equality of
opportunity, environmental protection, and maintenance of the social
safety net. Professional standards have broken down, and conflicts of
interest have proliferated. Correcting these deficiencies will require
stronger government intervention. Interestingly, the measure that is
likely to be most effective in clearing the air is the recent directive
issued by the SEC requiring the chief executive and financial officers of
the 947 largest companies to certify their accounts dating back to the
beginning of the previous fiscal year. The officers could be held
criminally liable if the accounts do not give a fair representation of the
company's financial condition--even if they are in conformity with the
GAAP . The directive is sufficiently vague so that the officers are likely
to err on the side of caution and reveal all questionable practices. It
reasserts the supremacy of broad principles over particular rules. In
doing so it harks back to the glory days of the SEC pre-dating Mike Milken
when principles like insider trading and stock manipulation were not yet
codified by court decisions.
Legislation is only part of the answer. Changes in the law must be
accompanied by a fundamental change of attitude. In the last analysis,
professional standards can be maintained only by the professions
themselves, and conflicts of interest can be avoided only if people
recognize a common interest other than self-interest. Without such a
change of heart, new regulation and new legislation will only encourage
more evasion.
It is unrealistic to expect that all market participants will suddenly
undergo such an ethical conversion. But public opinion and public
discourse--as we saw in the '90s--can have a dramatic impact on individual
behavior. Americans must relearn the difference between a collection of
individuals each pursuing his or her self-interest and a society of people
guided by the public interest. How well Americans relearn that difference
may well determine whether this country and the world return to economic
stability and prosperity in the months and years to come.