The first is how to measure emissions reductions relative to “business-as-usual”. This is essential: (i) for ensuring the effectiveness of the subsidy-based approach; and (ii) for its efficiency - deciding who is eligible for the subsidies, and for how much.
This is difficult. It requires quantification of the “counterfactual” situation, (i.e., what would have happened in the absence of the subsidy scheme) in order to determine how much emissions have been reduced. There’s great potential for “rorting”. (Look at responses to environmental incentives in Australia, such as for home insulation, or in PNG.)
The CPRS tax approach “only” requires measuring actual emissions produced. This is hard. Good as Australia is on this, “carbon accounting” is still a work-in-progress. But the CPRS does not require estimation of the (unobservable) business-as-usual emissions path as well.
Advertisement
The second problem is Australia’s World Trade Organisation (WTO) obligations. When do production subsidies applied to selected Australian exports (for example, agriculture) become behind-the-border protection, inviting WTO action?
If farmers aren’t directly penalised by having to buy emissions permits for the greenhouse gases they produce, but can get “carbon offsets” for emissions reducing activities, can they “make money” in net terms out of the deal? If they can, are they getting export subsidies? If they are, that’s protectionist. Australia’s not the worst offender on agricultural protectionism, but increasing it hardly aids our campaign to reduce it overseas.
If others follow, this might clog up the WTO with an avalanche of trade rule breaches, souring the global trading environment and slowing world growth. At worst, we send a signal for others to use the cover of a “green” policy (with exemptions) to veer further into old-style protectionist habits. The global economic crisis has already stimulated such action around the world (and here). We don’t need to encourage it further.
Finally, how does Australia pay for large emissions reduction subsidies?
Financially, taxing emissions and subsidising emissions reductions are different.
Taxing emissions delivers revenue that can be used to finance reductions in other taxes, increases in subsidies, or increases in transfer payments to lower income groups. The focus is raising relative prices for emissions intensive products, not reducing real incomes. However, the extra revenue only lasts as long as emissions continue, and declines as they decline.
Advertisement
Subsidising emissions reduction is different. There’s no immediate source of extra revenue. The costs of reducing emissions must be paid for out of existing income and revenues.
If we are currently consuming our environment unsustainably, but don’t feel this because there’s no price on emissions, this makes sense. The benefit we pay for is a better environment later.
Subsidies should just offset the extra cost of producing goods and services with fewer emissions, compared with current technologies.
Emissions reduction subsidies increase Budget costs. These will be passed on in higher taxes and charges, or reduced government spending.
Will farmers get net “carbon offsets” via the detailed regulations if the CPRS legislation is passed?
I wouldn’t bet on it.
Discuss in our Forums
See what other readers are saying about this article!
Click here to read & post comments.
5 posts so far.