Like what you've read?

On Line Opinion is the only Australian site where you get all sides of the story. We don't
charge, but we need your support. Here�s how you can help.

  • Advertise

    We have a monthly audience of 70,000 and advertising packages from $200 a month.

  • Volunteer

    We always need commissioning editors and sub-editors.

  • Contribute

    Got something to say? Submit an essay.


 The National Forum   Donate   Your Account   On Line Opinion   Forum   Blogs   Polling   About   
On Line Opinion logo ON LINE OPINION - Australia's e-journal of social and political debate

Subscribe!
Subscribe





On Line Opinion is a not-for-profit publication and relies on the generosity of its sponsors, editors and contributors. If you would like to help, contact us.
___________

Syndicate
RSS/XML


RSS 2.0

What price 'comparable effort' on emissions trading?

By Geoff Carmody - posted Thursday, 22 October 2009


What would happen if we actually got a global deal on emissions reduction in Copenhagen? Much of the commentary has been on reasons why we won’t. But suspend disbelief just for a moment and consider the implications of “success”.

We’d need to have sorted out who should bear what emissions abatement burden, and how such burdens should be measured (the “comparable effort” debate).

The deal would be national target-based.

Advertisement

On measurement of adjustment burdens, all sorts of emissions reduction metrics have been proposed: reductions relative to some baseline year, reductions relative to “business-as-usual” (BAU) in future, per capita emissions reductions, and others.

There’s been no consensus so far. This has helped prevent an effective global deal on climate policy. But let’s dream on. Even if all countries actually cut a “comparable effort” deal in December, there’s one small problem. It wouldn’t work. Especially if an emissions trading scheme (ETS), a market-based option, is pursued to deliver emissions abatement burden sharing, any “comparable effort” deal will be (an unlikely) Pyrrhic victory.

Do a simple thought experiment. Assume a global deal allocates precise emissions reductions to every country. Assume every country introduces an ETS-based emissions “cap” sufficient to deliver these reductions. Every country faces significant greenhouse gas emissions prices. However, there’s zero chance these prices will be the same in every country.

Targets have been negotiated based on the quantity-focused measures noted above. They’ve probably ignored emissions intensities of national resource endowments. Even if they try to allow for these, they aren’t designed to equalise emissions prices globally.

Now, under this hypothetical agreement, ETS models (for example, the CPRS) go to work.

Global trade in emissions permits drives “carbon arbitrage” between countries. Permit buyers go to lowest-price markets first. Prices there rise. Sellers move to highest-price markets. The high prices in countries with the toughest targets (mainly developed economies) fall.

Advertisement

Countries with above-average emissions prices don’t meet their emissions targets, “importing” emissions permits from low-price countries. The latter exceed agreed emissions reductions. In the former, emissions prices settle lower than targets warrant. In the latter group, they end up higher.

Compliance with agreed national targets is undermined as national allocations of permits shift through “carbon arbitrage” trading between countries. A globally uniform emissions price is established as a result of this arbitrage. The actual distribution of emissions reductions shifts to reflect this.

Market forces, working through the ETS itself, undermine national emissions reduction targets negotiated in ignorance of their market implications.

Globally, the same emissions reduction would be delivered. However, these “carbon arbitrage” developments will shuffle agreed emissions reduction burdens from rich to poor countries, destroying the carefully negotiated pattern of national emissions reductions comprising the global deal. This will probably end up destroying the deal itself.

If this outcome is foreseeable, assuming success in Copenhagen is unrealistic.

By definition, ETS supporters believe in market forces. If so, we’d better focus on how policies like the ETS and carbon taxes aim to reduce emissions: by increasing their price. Emissions prices tend to equilibrate under market forces.

Emissions prices have another advantage. National emissions prices are more easily discovered, making assessment of “comparable effort” easier.

There’s a better way to benchmark “comparable efforts” and reduce impediments to a global deal. Focus on emissions prices and on national emissions consumption, not production.

Sharing the adjustment burden between rich and poor countries (the former having higher per capita consumption “carbon footprints” and therefore higher per capita adjustment costs) would be easier.

Differences in national comparative advantage based on energy sources with high greenhouse gas emissions would be covered fairly. If there’s a global deal, reduced comparative advantage associated with large greenhouse gas emissions is greatest for countries well endowed with such resources.

For countries like Australia, adjustment burden and resource allocation effects would follow one of two paths.

Without a global deal, Australia’s trade comparative advantage is minimally affected.

With a global deal, Australians face two above-average adjustment burdens. We have high per capita emissions consumption. Our comparative advantage is based partly on endowments of emissions-intensive energy. A global deal ensures Australians, per capita, pay substantially for emissions. Fair enough. To suggest Australians should pay without such a global deal is nationally irresponsible.

Why pursue the current targets-based model? Success via agreement on the national distribution of emissions permits immediately produces failure via “carbon arbitrage”.

Want a good, practical, reasonably objective, pretty fair, indicator of national emissions abatement “comparable effort”?

It’s the price paid for national emissions consumption in each country

  1. Pages:
  2. 1
  3. 2
  4. All

First published in the Australian Financial Review on October 15, 2009.



Discuss in our Forums

See what other readers are saying about this article!

Click here to read & post comments.

5 posts so far.

Share this:
reddit this reddit thisbookmark with del.icio.us Del.icio.usdigg thisseed newsvineSeed NewsvineStumbleUpon StumbleUponsubmit to propellerkwoff it

About the Author

Geoff Carmody was a director of Geoff Carmody & Associates, a former co-founder of Access Economics, and before that was a senior officer in the Commonwealth Treasury. He died on October 27, 2024. He favoured a national consumption-based climate policy, preferably using a carbon tax to put a price on carbon. He has prepared papers entitled Effective climate change policy: the seven Cs. Paper #1: Some design principles for evaluating greenhouse gas abatement policies. Paper #2: Implementing design principles for effective climate change policy. Paper #3: ETS or carbon tax?

Other articles by this Author

All articles by Geoff Carmody

Creative Commons LicenseThis work is licensed under a Creative Commons License.

Article Tools
Comment 5 comments
Print Printable version
Subscribe Subscribe
Email Email a friend
Advertisement

About Us Search Discuss Feedback Legals Privacy