Like what you've read?

On Line Opinion is the only Australian site where you get all sides of the story. We don't
charge, but we need your support. Here�s how you can help.

  • Advertise

    We have a monthly audience of 70,000 and advertising packages from $200 a month.

  • Volunteer

    We always need commissioning editors and sub-editors.

  • Contribute

    Got something to say? Submit an essay.


 The National Forum   Donate   Your Account   On Line Opinion   Forum   Blogs   Polling   About   
On Line Opinion logo ON LINE OPINION - Australia's e-journal of social and political debate

Subscribe!
Subscribe





On Line Opinion is a not-for-profit publication and relies on the generosity of its sponsors, editors and contributors. If you would like to help, contact us.
___________

Syndicate
RSS/XML


RSS 2.0

Paying mothers to have children must stop

By Jason Falinski - posted Wednesday, 11 January 2006


Gary S. Becker is a Nobel Prize-winning economist from the Chicago School. His revolutionary idea was that people, often unbeknown to themselves, make decisions on the basis of a cost-benefit analysis. For instance, whether to marry or commit crimes are subjected to this analysis.

The implications of the Becker theory were not immediately apparent, but over time governments grasped the policy implications. It meant that if you wanted to reduce crime then you needed to either lower the benefits of crime or increase the costs.

(Unfortunately, governments misapplied this theory. Becker made it clear that most people break laws after assessing the likelihood of getting caught. This includes violent crime, speeding and illegal parking. The costs are almost incidental as most people who infringe laws assume that the cost is zero because they have already figured that the likelihood of discovery is very small. In other words, the best way to reduce crime is to increase the likelihood of capture.)

Advertisement

Becker also turned to the question of welfare and how it impacted on people’s behaviour. His most controversial conclusion regarded the single mother pension. In short, Becker showed that if you pay single mothers on the basis of the number of children they have, you create an incentive for single parents to have more children. It has been shown that this causes more harm in health, educational, employment, life expectancy, crime outcomes and so on.

This analysis more than anything else drove the conservative agenda in the US calling for welfare reform. For decades progressive thinkers, on both the Left and the Right, argued vehemently against single mother benefits because of the harm it was causing children. Conservative Left-wingers contended that stopping single mother payments would only hurt the capability of single mothers to look after their children.

Under Bill Clinton and Newt Gingrich, single mother benefits were moved away from payments on the basis of the number of children towards helping single mothers find employment through upskilling and child care provisions. Once again this change was contemplated because a substantial amount of research showed that children brought up in households where the provider had some form of employment had better health, employment and educational outcomes.

This debate was reflected in Australia in the lead up to the 1996 federal election when several Liberal politicians criticised the Keating Government’s $500 upfront payment to pregnant women. Their criticism was largely based on Becker’s analysis.

Little research was done on the impact of the Keating initiative, however, anecdotal evidence from social workers was that the program created substantial incentives among welfare recipients to have more children regardless of their capability to provide for more children.

Given the weight of research: why would a government provide an incentive for parents to have more children? Such schemes are curious and perplexing. A so-called baby bonus would have the policy purpose of helping to ease the financial burden of the birth of a child. This is presumably to improve fertility rates in Australia.

Advertisement

However, what Becker’s analysis shows is that this payment is likely to impact most effectively with people on lower and fixed incomes. Those people on higher incomes, for whom the payment is somewhat negligible, would not consider it a relevant factor in their benefit cost analysis. On the other hand, people on welfare would find the benefit cost analysis substantially improved.

And who are those on the lowest and fixed incomes? Single parent households. The very same households that decades of research have shown were most badly served by a policy of paying mothers for having children. It would be interesting to see which areas have had a substantial increase in births in the past few years.

For many women the cost of having a child is the time taken out of the workforce, the isolation of raising a child in the early years, and the difficulty of finding adequate, affordable and flexible childcare when they want to re-enter the workforce. Substantially reducing these costs, as has been done in Scandinavian countries, is probably a better and healthier way to improve Australia’s fertility rate.

  1. Pages:
  2. Page 1
  3. 2
  4. All


Discuss in our Forums

See what other readers are saying about this article!

Click here to read & post comments.

111 posts so far.

Share this:
reddit this reddit thisbookmark with del.icio.us Del.icio.usdigg thisseed newsvineSeed NewsvineStumbleUpon StumbleUponsubmit to propellerkwoff it

About the Author

Jason Falinski is managing director of CareWell a provider of furniture and equipment to the health sector, and a former national president of the Young Liberal Movement.

Other articles by this Author

All articles by Jason Falinski

Creative Commons LicenseThis work is licensed under a Creative Commons License.

Photo of Jason Falinski
Article Tools
Comment 111 comments
Print Printable version
Subscribe Subscribe
Email Email a friend
Advertisement

About Us Search Discuss Feedback Legals Privacy