The Federal Government has failed to adapt to the improved economic environment and must implement more structural changes.
When in 1980-81 I headed the Treasury division advising on the budget, our principal concern was to persuade the government that the major policy priority should be to reduce inflation (then about 10 per cent per annum) by constraining demand through reductions in the budget deficit and monetary growth.
Then Treasurer John Howard announced an estimated deficit of 1.5 per cent of GDP (well down on the 5 per cent deficit emanating from the last disastrous year of 1975-76 under the Whitlam Government) and emphasised “unless we persist in our fight against inflation our full economic potential will not be realised”. The budget papers clearly indicated, however, that Treasury was unhappy that most of the large increase in estimated revenue was being spent, leading to an increase in outlays as a proportion of GDP, and that more had not been done to reduce the budget call on both real and financial resources.
Advertisement
Fast forward 25 years, and we find that John Howard as prime minister faces different - and vastly improved - budget and economic policy situations to those he experienced as treasurer. With the help of much improved monetary and external policy institutional arrangements, the serious problems posed by inflation have been brought under control and the Coalition Government has adopted a medium-term budget strategy to maintain, on average, balance over the economic cycle. In fact, with sustained economic growth and no downward turn in the economic cycle, it has been running budget surpluses that, with the proceeds of privatisations, have almost eliminated debt and even raised the question - what to do with the surplus cash?
This medium-term, budget-balance approach is also reflected in the recognition that economic analysis is not sufficiently robust to warrant making either budget or monetary policy changes designed to fine tune the rate of economic growth. Indeed, Treasury Secretary Ken Henry even pointed out in a recent address, “It is well nigh impossible to forecast the macroeconomy for years beyond the budget year” - and if you can’t make such forecasts, it is difficult to justify policy changes that have lagged effects, but are directed at increasing or reducing growth in the period not far ahead.
Associated with this recognition is the increased acceptance among economists that, providing institutional budget and monetary arrangements are in good shape, there is now a much greater likelihood the private sector will itself adjust to structural changes in Australia or overseas, without experiencing the up or down fluctuations in the economy that involve recessions or unsustainable booms.
Again, Ken Henry pointed out recent strong growth in export prices (principally resulting from the strong growth in Chinese demand) has led to appreciation in the exchange rate that has dampened the growth in export incomes and by encouraging imports, has reduced the pressure on domestic resources and on inflation.
In short, changes to Australia’s external institutional arrangements have provided an “automatic” adjusting mechanism to externally driven structural change and in combination with budgetary and monetary institutional arrangements, has reduced what might in earlier times have prompted changes in budgetary and or monetary policies. Accordingly, while sticking to the budget surplus approach, this has allowed the government to announce additional tax cuts and increased spending in the 2005-06 Budget without running a serious risk inflationary pressures would emerge. Indeed, as (post-budget) it now appears that Australia is experiencing a slowing in economic growth that was not forecast, any addition to demand from tax cuts may well be welcome.
So, is everything in the budgetary scene hunky dory? Well, not quite. The Budget included what Henry described as a strengthening of recent efforts by the government to “re-engage with the workforce those on disability support pension and the parenting payment programs [and] over time raise the labour force participation of many individuals on these programs, lifting aggregate participation outcomes”. But Henry was being rather kind to what was a very poor start by the government to tackling the need to reduce the proportion of the population receiving social benefits and lift the proportion working. As the Treasury’s Intergenerational Report of 2002-03 pointed out, without policy changes, the ageing of the population will mean lower growth in employment and hence, in living standards.
Advertisement
In these circumstances, and with the strong growth in per capita incomes over recent years, it is absurd to have 2.7 million or 20 per cent of the working age population receiving income support compared with only 15 per cent at the end of the 1980s and 4 per cent in 1969. Social assistance benefits alone now contribute 14.3 per cent of gross household disposable income, compared with just 8 per cent under the Whitlam Government.
Indeed, with increased standards of health and education, individuals are more able to take care of themselves and the proportion of the population needing Commonwealth welfare and health assistance should have been falling - and should be continuing to do so. A progressive reduction in the proportion receiving government assistance would make a major contribution to dealing with the longer-term problem identified in the Intergenerational Report.
But the need for corrective action is not simply related to the ageing problem. The OECD’s 2004 Economic Survey of Australia brought that home when it said: