Like what you've read?

On Line Opinion is the only Australian site where you get all sides of the story. We don't
charge, but we need your support. Here�s how you can help.

  • Advertise

    We have a monthly audience of 70,000 and advertising packages from $200 a month.

  • Volunteer

    We always need commissioning editors and sub-editors.

  • Contribute

    Got something to say? Submit an essay.


 The National Forum   Donate   Your Account   On Line Opinion   Forum   Blogs   Polling   About   
On Line Opinion logo ON LINE OPINION - Australia's e-journal of social and political debate

Subscribe!
Subscribe





On Line Opinion is a not-for-profit publication and relies on the generosity of its sponsors, editors and contributors. If you would like to help, contact us.
___________

Syndicate
RSS/XML


RSS 2.0

'Privatising' Aboriginal land is no panacea

By Jennifer Clarke - posted Friday, 15 April 2005


Jurisdictions which prevent the transfer of freehold title to Aboriginal land may still allow commercially valuable leases to be created over it. Besides the Ghan leases, the NT Act allows Aboriginal land to be leased to commercial housing developers and providers, including Aboriginal companies. If it doesn’t already permit individual Aboriginal lessees to mortgage residential leases to raise money to build houses, a minor amendment would correct the anomaly.

But in remote Northern Territory Aboriginal communities, do people really have the income to support mortgages? Most are unemployed. Many are single mothers who, unlike many single mothers in Sydney, do not receive child support payments from ex-partners. Nearly half of Wadeye’s residents are non-income-earning children. Annual adult income in Wadeye is about $12,000, depending on whether you have kids: to gain access to the NT’s low-income housing loans scheme, three adults will have to club together. A depressingly large number of Aboriginal men in particular do not live long enough, or stay out of jail long enough, to pay off a 25-year mortgage.

Any property market in Wadeye is likely to be an artificial one, but the costs of a house may be higher than they first appear. Not only are construction costs high for transport and seasonal reasons, but traditional owners, like other Australian property owners, may understandably seek some return by way of rent.

Advertisement

While joint ownership of houses may be culturally appropriate, in a culture which obliges you to share resources on demand, joint mortgages could get pretty onerous. And what happens if the mortgage is defaulted on? Are people who’ve lived in Wadeye all their lives to be evicted? If so, they will probably do what Aboriginal people do when evicted from public housing - move in with their relatives. The alternative is to go somewhere else, usually town. Are towns like Katherine and Darwin ready for an increase in Aboriginal homelessness? Should we be concerned that home equity refunds might not be reinvested under such stressful conditions?

Then there is the ongoing maintenance problem, which Senator Vanstone’s DIY scheme does not address. Do plumbers and electricians service remote communities regularly? You bet they don’t. Can you duck down to Bunnings or Kennards when the sink blocks up? No, you have to swim with it. Can you order a plunger over the internet? Wadeye residents may be about to obtain the computers and skills to do this, but without credit cards, imagination may still be required to find the funds.

Even ignoring the effects of evictions, remote Aboriginal houses are usually full for cultural reasons. This increased strain on housing stock means that a person - or a bank - who has “invested” in Wadeye property, even on a 99-year lease, may find it impossible to realise that investment later.

The main villain here is not, as Helen Hughes and Jenness Warin have argued, frozen property rights or the permit system, but Australia’s highly urbanised distribution of population and wealth. Even if there are enough people and enough housing problems in remote communities to keep a tradesperson in regular work, there isn’t enough money to attract the service there from places where people can pay more. If permits were barriers to commerce, they would keep the snake oil, vacuum cleaner and life insurance salesmen out - as well as genuine traders.

Perhaps it is good social policy to force the traditional owners of land rights land to lease it for Aboriginal housing, as Mundine has suggested. This may be particularly true where traditional owners hold a lot of land. It may even be desirable to restrict the amount of rent which traditional owners claim from unlanded Aborigines who have lived on their country since “equal wages” pushed them off their own country on pastoral stations, although kinship links and the land’s low value may impose their own limits.

But why stop there? Why not require tradespeople to provide services, hardware stores to provide goods, and banks to provide low-interest loans? Why should the burden of Aboriginal poverty be reallocated only to other Aborigines? Isn’t this just selective “socialism” in another guise?

Advertisement

History shows where the limits should be drawn on plans to “privatise” Aboriginal land. In the 19th century, Congress legislated to divide US Indian reservations into individual “allotments”. This plan’s results revealed objectives beyond the assimilationist one of converting hunters into farmers. First, government was thereby licensed to sell off “surplus” Indian land. And secondly, impoverished native Americans eventually did the same with their only valuable assets.

Malaysia's experience illustrates the likely consequences of creating a more limited market in Aboriginal freehold. There, land was made alienable, but only to other "natives". The result was the emergence of a native landholding class at the expense of those who lacked the resources to maintain title, a problem partly caused by the fact that banks refused to lend against land which, as non-"natives", they couldn't repossess.

Even if it is possible to convert people whose culture values housing mainly for its social utility into property investors, if Wadeye’s social marginalisation is not addressed at the same time, its residents will remain “dirt poor”. It is important that they don’t become “land poor” as well.

  1. Pages:
  2. 1
  3. Page 2
  4. All


Discuss in our Forums

See what other readers are saying about this article!

Click here to read & post comments.

20 posts so far.

Share this:
reddit this reddit thisbookmark with del.icio.us Del.icio.usdigg thisseed newsvineSeed NewsvineStumbleUpon StumbleUponsubmit to propellerkwoff it

About the Author

Jennifer Clarke is a Canberra lawyer

Other articles by this Author

All articles by Jennifer Clarke

Creative Commons LicenseThis work is licensed under a Creative Commons License.

Article Tools
Comment 20 comments
Print Printable version
Subscribe Subscribe
Email Email a friend
Advertisement

About Us Search Discuss Feedback Legals Privacy