Like what you've read?

On Line Opinion is the only Australian site where you get all sides of the story. We don't
charge, but we need your support. Here�s how you can help.

  • Advertise

    We have a monthly audience of 70,000 and advertising packages from $200 a month.

  • Volunteer

    We always need commissioning editors and sub-editors.

  • Contribute

    Got something to say? Submit an essay.


 The National Forum   Donate   Your Account   On Line Opinion   Forum   Blogs   Polling   About   
On Line Opinion logo ON LINE OPINION - Australia's e-journal of social and political debate

Subscribe!
Subscribe





On Line Opinion is a not-for-profit publication and relies on the generosity of its sponsors, editors and contributors. If you would like to help, contact us.
___________

Syndicate
RSS/XML


RSS 2.0

Has Australia lost its appetite for economic reform?

By Ross Garnaut - posted Tuesday, 10 August 2004


The 2004 election contest is premised confidently on continued prosperity. But a harder reality is likely to intrude before the next parliament has finished its work.

Since the 1991-92 recession, the economy has performed better than that of other rich countries for the first time. Economic growth in the 1990s was underpinned by the strongest export expansion in our history.  All of this began during the mid 80s, when there was for a while a broad-based acceptance that economic analysis was relevant to economic policy. This acceptance was a sharp departure from the earlier Australian political culture, which had weighed pressures from vested interests more heavily in the balance of economic policy-making. The crucial measures included financial market deregulation and reductions in import protection.

I do not come to the view that the comfortable times are fading from any general predilection to gloom. In Australia and the “northeast Asian ascendancy”, I challenged the political orthodoxy of the time in anticipating the lift in productivity as well as the export diversification and growth that would accompany the internationalisation of the Australian economy. As the Thai economy was falling into depression in late 1997 and the contagion spread through East Asia, I wrote in a paper for the Australian Business Council that we could expect continued strong growth for our economy.  Prime Minister John Howard, in speeches inside and outside parliament, broadcast the optimism that I expressed at The Australian's 1997 conference, "Australia Unlimited". I spoke then about the shock that Australians would soon experience as they realised they were part of the third period of sustained prosperity in their country's history.

Advertisement

I have long expressed the view that no economic expansion is doomed simply on account of its longevity.

Australia's biggest economic problems before the recent prosperity came mainly from two sources. The first was expansion of domestic expenditure beyond the productive capacity of the economy. Sometimes the unsustainable increase came from spending the benefits of increased export prices (terms of trade), which turned out to be temporary.  The second source of problems was policies that constrained the efficiency with which Australian resources were used. Low productivity growth sharpened the difficulty of holding expenditure within the economy's (diminished) capacity.

There has been a gradual erosion of support for action on productivity-raising reform during the past decade. Much of the legacy of the reform period remains, including a much more open economy, more competitive domestic markets, deep integration into Asian economies, an economically productive immigration program and a somewhat more flexible labour market.  But there is now little political interest in removing remaining barriers to Australian economic efficiency. A new low-water mark for the influence of economic analysis was reached last Saturday, when an editorial in support of the US free trade agreement in The Weekend Australian asserted that "economic sense and political reality are rarely related".

The decline in support for productivity-raising reform in Australia has already contributed to less efficient resource allocation. It would compound the costs of any economic downturn in the period ahead.  The problems from excessive demand expansion are already acute. For several years real private consumption and total domestic demand have risen more strongly than over any comparable extended period, and real public expenditure has not been held back to offset them. Private consumption has been driven by one of the strongest sustained real expansions of bank lending.

The real domestic demand expansion of recent years is at least as virulent as that which precipitated the extreme monetary tightening of the late 90s. The savings share of household income fell in the boom of the late 80s, but remained in the range of eight per cent to ten per cent. It was minus three percent in the March quarter of 2004.

We now know that interest rates were increased too much in the late 80s. That error should not be repeated. But to react too little to the problem that has emerged would be to err in another way, with different immediate but regrettably similar medium-term consequences.

Advertisement

The economist's starting point for assessing changes in international competitiveness is the ratio of prices of non-tradable (domestic) goods and services to those of tradables (exports and imports). In the March quarter of 2004 this ratio was higher than at any time during the two decades for which we have data, despite export prices being the highest over that period. The inflation in domestic prices seems now to be deeply entrenched near one percent per quarter - far higher than in any of Australia's large trading partners.  The extent of the ongoing domestic inflation has been obscured by falling prices for tradable goods in the year to February, reinforced by a rising currency.

The fall in the foreign exchange value of the Australian dollar since then brings inflation into sharper focus. The increases in Australian dollar prices of imports and exports in the June quarter will find their way into the broad-based indexes through the remainder of 2004.  One symptom of the extraordinary expansion of domestic demand has been a current account deficit near record levels as a proportion of gross domestic product, despite record terms of trade and historically low international interest rates.

The collapse since 2000 of the strong export growth that began with the reforms from the mid 80s is symptomatic of the corrosion of competitiveness.  From the March quarter of 1986 to the March quarter of 2001, the volume of Australian manufactured exports increased by more than 600 percent and of services by more than 200 percent. The volume of agricultural exports grew by about three quarters and resources by almost 200 percent over the same 15 years.

By contrast, over the three years from March 2001 to March 2004, the volume of manufactured exports increased by a total of four per cent and services by one per cent, while rural and resources exports both declined.

Defenders of the complacent view point to a number of specific causes of weak export growth in recent years: the drought of 2002; the effects on tourism of SARS and the Iraq war in the first half of 2003; and the US recession of 2001.  Yet closer analysis shows that by the March quarter of 2004, the record grain harvest of 2003 was making its way through the export terminals. International tourism had recovered strongly in the rest of the world. Economic recovery in the US, unexpected growth in Japan and the China boom helped to make the March quarter perhaps the strongest yet for imports into Australia's export markets.

The best groups of applied economists in Australia are in the Reserve Bank of Australia and the Treasury. Such is their intellectual dominance that private sector economists ensure their own forecasts do not vary much from those of these authorities. But even my friends in the bank and Treasury seem to have succumbed to the great Australian complacency of the early 21st. century.

In the May 2001 budget papers, Treasury forecast export volume growth of five percent - said to be a "little below trend". The next year's budget reported the outcome at minus two percent. The same forecast for 2002-03 was six percent. The reported outcome was zero. The forecast outcome for 2003-04 was again six percent. The outcome was reported the next year as two percent. So what do we make of the latest budget forecast of eight percent growth in export volumes?

The contemporary data provide reasons to expect new disappointments in the budget papers for 2005.

Domestic demand has to be reduced significantly from its present trajectory for a start to be made on correcting the dangerous imbalances in the economy. The anticipated correction in the housing market can deliver only part of the adjustment that is required.  The necessary policy adjustment would be less damaging to long-term growth the earlier it came. It would be least disruptive if it were led by a tightening of fiscal policy. But this is hardly likely in the febrile heights of a year-long election campaign - or soon after a campaign has been won by one party or the other by promising that the easy times will continue forever.

If budget surpluses were increased for the duration of the excessive domestic demand, monetary tightening would still be necessary, but would not have to go so far. The increases in interest rates would be less the earlier they came. Leave it too late and the markets will impose their own sudden and disruptive solution. But judiciously timed monetary policy, too, is constrained by the year-long election campaign.  When it comes, the tightening of monetary policy will temporarily exacerbate the problem of competitiveness, by lifting the dollar (or, more likely, constraining the fall that would otherwise be associated with the weak external payments). Like it or not, sustainable, non-inflationary improvements in competitiveness may be preceded by what seems a backward step.

Is there no happy ending? Won't the China boom, with India to follow, avoid the need for adjustment by continuing to raise our terms of trade?

Without Chinese growth, we may have had a crisis before now. But the China boom of early 2004 is about as good as it gets. We will indeed be the lucky country if the terms of trade hold at their present high levels. The next period of sustained prosperity, like the one that is now fading, will be made in Australia.

  1. Pages:
  2. 1
  3. 2
  4. All

Article edited by Betsy Fysh.
If you'd like to be a volunteer editor too, click here.

This article was previously published in The Australian  on 29th. July, 2004.



Discuss in our Forums

See what other readers are saying about this article!

Click here to read & post comments.

Share this:
reddit this reddit thisbookmark with del.icio.us Del.icio.usdigg thisseed newsvineSeed NewsvineStumbleUpon StumbleUponsubmit to propellerkwoff it

About the Author

Ross Garnaut is Professor of Economics at the Australian National University.

Related Links
The Australian
Article Tools
Comment Comments
Print Printable version
Subscribe Subscribe
Email Email a friend
Advertisement

About Us Search Discuss Feedback Legals Privacy