For decades now, at least since the Murray report in the 1950s, we’ve
assumed that more people going to university is a good thing. Governments
boast about the number of student places they’ve created and blame
others when, despite a growing student body, some applicants still miss
out. The Australian Vice-Chancellors’ Committee has set a year 2020
target for 60 per cent of Australians to possess a higher-education
qualification. As just over 30 per cent of today’s 19-year-olds are at
university, that would require a big boost in school leavers going on to
university, and many mature-age students.
In a recent and provocative book Does Education Matter?, Alison
Wolf, a British academic, argues that at least from an economic point of
view, expanding higher education is not always desirable. The labour
market genuinely needs only so many graduates. Surplus graduates encourage
credential inflation, since employers know they can demand higher
qualification levels than jobs require. This pushes less qualified but
perfectly competent people into lower skill jobs or unemployment.
Expanding higher education beyond a certain point is at best wasteful, and
at worst positively harmful for those unable or unwilling to attend
university.
In Australia, there is a plausible argument that we have reached the
point at which expansion should stop. Labour market surveys suggest that
about 20 per cent of graduates work in jobs that do not require degrees,
such as clerical, retail and labouring occupations. This number is
supported by an opinion survey which found 19 per cent of graduates
thought their degree was not necessary for the job they did.
Advertisement
However, snapshot-in-time numbers need to be treated with caution. Even
when similar results are found in multiple surveys, it does not mean that
we are looking at the same people every time. Just because a graduate
holds a lower-skill job today, it does not mean that is true of a year ago
or a year hence. Adults with family responsibilities may deliberately
though temporarily absent themselves from more demanding jobs. The
inevitable ups and downs of the labour market mean that some graduates end
up in low-skill occupations between other jobs. Nevertheless, there is no
evidence in these numbers that we need more graduates.
Other labour market data suggests that current flows of graduates are
largely adequate, and there is no need for more. Only in a few occupations
have we seen sustained labour market shortages, most seriously in nursing.
While more graduates are probably part of the solution here, the main
problem is low pay and poor retention rates once in the workforce, not
anything universities are doing. The added students places could be
created by moving places from areas such as Arts, with chronic
underemployment problems, rather than creating new places.
While labour market forecasting results must be viewed sceptically,
predictions of future demand for graduates similarly offer no support for
the argument in favour of more graduates. A few years ago, as part of its
education campaign, the ALP commissioned the Centre for Policy Studies to
predict future demand for graduates. They forecast 550,000 extra jobs for
graduates in the period 1997-2010. Labor seemed to take this as a case for
more university places. But even at current completion rates more than
1,000,000 Australians will graduate from university in that period. Even
if the CPS seriously understates future demand, we will still have more
graduates than the labour market needs.
Another reason to doubt that more university students makes sense is
that the quality of the untapped school-leaver pool is too low. Even among
those Year 12 students who now apply for university, many have mediocre
results. The problem is particularly acute for students from government
schools in low and middle socio-economic status areas. The ENTER system is
now used for school leaver university admissions. It ranks students, with
a highest possible rank of 99.95. Victorian government school university
applicants from middle SES areas in 2000 achieved a median score of 59.85,
and from low SES areas 49.90. The historical record is that university
completion rates starting dropping off significantly below the top 30 per
cent of school leavers. Encouraging more students with results like these
to try university will leave a significant portion of them with a HECS
debt and feelings of failure, not a passport to high-paying jobs.
All four funding models the Commonwealth suggests in its recent
discussion paper on university finance deal with graduate oversupply by
restricting the total number of subsidised student places. The problem,
however, is their mechanisms for distributing those places. Distributing
by university, as proposed in their first two models, disregards student
preferences and undermines competition, both of which contribute
substantially to the system’s current mediocrity. Distributing places to
students based on Year 12 scores, as suggested in the government’s
second two models, means information about student aptitude and
motivation, along with universities’ willingness to provide marginal
students with support, is ignored. So Year 12 students with no interest in
university education would be awarded subsidies, while keen prospective
students with slightly weaker school results miss out.
To allocate student places effectively we need universities and
students deciding who goes on to higher education, not governments. One
possibility for enhancing their decision-making is to establish
higher-education brokers, people with good knowledge both of the available
courses and of individual students, to give prospective students realistic
advice about their options and prospects. The Commonwealth has suggested
more students do at least their first year in TAFE, with the possibility
of receiving a credential at the end of first or second year. This would
get students into post-secondary education without committing them to a
degree programme to which they may be unsuited. This proposal is also well
worth considering.
Advertisement
On the available evidence, the results of more university graduates are
likely to be increasing the unemployment risk of workers without degrees,
higher university failure rates, students with HECS debts but no
qualifications, and the opportunity cost of money spent on extra students
that could have been spent on something of greater social value. The onus
is on the Australian Vice-Chancellors’ Committee, and other advocates of
greater participation in higher education, to defend targets that seem to
have been plucked out of the air, without regard for the economic or
social consequences.