But even on its own figures, the Israeli government’s funding of innovation, of itself, doesn’t appear to yield particularly spectacular results.
One figure that is often quoted is that for every shekel of government research and development money, one and half shekels are spent on private R&D. That looks like a pretty average return. And while Israel’s chief scientist is given a wad of cash to hand out to promote innovation, it is actually a pretty small sum (and not what our ‘‘don’t worry about the money’’ Prime Minister probably has in mind.)
One of the problems of formulating a policy on innovation, assuming for a moment that it’s a good idea, is how innovation is defined. The government seems to be far too keen to link the idea of innovation to start-ups, information technology and science. There also is some confusion between R&D and innovation.
Advertisement
The definition I like the best is along the following lines: the process of translating an idea or invention into a good or service that creates value for which customers will pay or better value for taxpayers. But it is important to note that innovation is not always about new products or services; process innovation is arguably as, if not more, important.
Innovation is not just about commercialising research. It is also about taking new technologies and using them. Australia doesn’t seem to be very good at the former but is good at the latter. That may be no bad thing because we have not borne the costs of developing the new technologies but are happy to implement them. And note that innovation can and does occur in existing firms, not just new ones.
So what should we expect to be in Father Innovation’s sack? The first thing we will have to bear is some long-winded guff about the importance of innovation. My advice is to skip that section of the statement.
Hopefully, there will be a frank assessment of the factors that are holding back innovation in Australia. These include the income tax and capital gains regime; inappropriate and excessive regulation; unsuitable industrial relations laws; and higher education institutions that lack the incentives to be involved with practical innovation. For example, we have not truly sorted out the problems with the taxation of employee share options or crowd-sourced funding.
Share options are used extensively in Silicon Valley to allow companies to save precious cash as well as create strong performance incentives for workers.
Our highly progressive income tax scales mean that if an entrepreneur does succeed, they quickly will be paying nearly 50c in the dollar for all that effort and risk-taking. On top of that, Australia has a high rate of capital gains tax by international standards. Both these factors are likely to be important in determining whether an entrepreneur chooses to locate here.
Advertisement
Taxation arrangements targeting R&D and innovation are likely to figure prominently in the statement. There is considerable disagreement about the extent to which R&D tax concessions really contribute to innovation — or at least spending on R&D that would not happen otherwise.
There is the British experiment with patent boxes in which the company profits attributable to patents and licences are levied at the rate of 10 per cent. But the evidence there is that patent boxes are often gamed by companies with no net addition to the number of patents.
Something that is often mentioned in the context of promoting innovation is the law related to bankruptcy. Should we move to US Chapter 11 bankruptcy-style arrangements in which creditors quickly lose their money but the company can continue to operate?
Discuss in our Forums
See what other readers are saying about this article!
Click here to read & post comments.
5 posts so far.