Like what you've read?

On Line Opinion is the only Australian site where you get all sides of the story. We don't
charge, but we need your support. Here�s how you can help.

  • Advertise

    We have a monthly audience of 70,000 and advertising packages from $200 a month.

  • Volunteer

    We always need commissioning editors and sub-editors.

  • Contribute

    Got something to say? Submit an essay.


 The National Forum   Donate   Your Account   On Line Opinion   Forum   Blogs   Polling   About   
On Line Opinion logo ON LINE OPINION - Australia's e-journal of social and political debate

Subscribe!
Subscribe





On Line Opinion is a not-for-profit publication and relies on the generosity of its sponsors, editors and contributors. If you would like to help, contact us.
___________

Syndicate
RSS/XML


RSS 2.0

The revolt of the magic pudding: sharing care in Australia

By Nancy Folbre - posted Monday, 15 April 2002


One of the most important things I’ve learned in Australia is the story of The Magic Pudding. According to Norman Lindsay’s classic children’s tale, a lovable but rather clueless group of males come into possession of a Magic Pudding that provides a limitless supply of food. No matter how much they eat, ample supply always remains. The pudding in question is rather cranky, and occasionally tries to run away. In the end, however, it is fenced in to its own little paddock in a tree house, firmly in the possession of the Society of Puddin’ Owners.

Times have changed since this story was published in 1918. We know now that the pudding is not really named Albert. It’s real name is Mother. It metaphorically represents the source of feminine altruism that has provided the major supply of care for children, the sick, and the elderly, and also many working age adults. This supply remains magical in its ability to meet the needs of its loved ones. But it is not (and never has been) inexhaustible. Indeed, there are many signs that it is wearing thin.

It’s not hard to imagine why. Consider who you would like to be when you grow up: Bunyip Bluegum, free to venture out into the world with nothing but a walking stick, or Magic Pudding, a captive in a cookpot available to meet everyone else’s needs.

Advertisement

Over the years of venturing into the world, feminists have learned not only that women have a long way to go to achieve equal rights, but also that equal rights are not enough. Men and women have equal obligations to care for dependents, as well as equal rights to pursue their own priorities. We need to rethink our ‘social family contract’.

The ‘invisible heart’

Conventional economic theory has misled us. Our economic accounting systems value market transactions but ignore the value of natural assets and non-market work. Thus, any shift of resources from non-market to market is a shift from ‘uncounted’ to ‘counted’:

  • A company saves money by dumping unprocessed wastes into the environment, because it averts a cost that would otherwise be counted against its revenues. The cost to current and future generations goes uncounted.
  • Adults increase their hours of paid work, increasing both family income and Gross Domestic Product. But the reduction of time they might otherwise have devoted to raising children or caring for their elderly or disabled members goes uncounted.
  • Individuals who conform to the ‘ideal worker’ image – unencumbered by family responsibilities enjoy high wages and rapid promotion. Individuals who fulfill commitments to their families and communities get the message that they are less ‘competitive’ and less valuable to society. Yet, without the unpaid care these individuals provide, society would fall apart.

Markets can do a good job of coordinating the choices of autonomous, self-interested individuals. They cannot do a good job of coordinating the care and nurturance of dependents who are not free to choose. For this, we need families and States that offer mutual support for one another within a larger social democratic polity.

Families alone cannot do the job, because competitive markets penalise those who devote themselves to the production of unpriced goods. The very expansion of opportunities and choices in the market increases the ‘opportunity cost’ of time devoted to activities of public rather than purely private benefit.

Advertisement

It is sometimes popular to argue that the decision to raise a child is nothing more than a discretionary form of consumption, like raising a kelpie. Why then, should taxpayers be asked to support it? ‘You propagate, you pay’! Perfect market-based reasoning. But most pets do not grow up to become taxpayers, workers or citizens. And market goods are subsidised by mothers and fathers who do the non-market work of raising children. Every time you hire a wage earner, or buy a product that was produced by a wage earner, you are benefiting from the altruistic contributions of the parents, other family members, and poorly paid care workers who developed that worker’s capabilities.

The analogy in a robot-based economy, would be consumers paying for the batteries and spare parts needed to keep robots going, but not for the actual cost of producing them. This is because intrinsically motivated robot-makers were willing to charge only a token amount for their services. One might expect such robot-makers to tire of providing free services to robot-users, as the opportunity cost of their intrinsically motivated activities goes up.

No wonder fertility in Australia, as in many other countries, is now far below replacement level.

Sharing the care

Recently, Australian academics have been vigorously debating whether policy should provide a greater family allowance for parents or greater public provision of child care. But this is, to some extent, a false debate. Social policy should not force us to choose between more support for family caregivers and support for paid care. Both are needed and the care should be shared around.

Australia offers both modest tax support for childrearing and some publicly provided care. But these expenditures, (or rather, ‘investments’) are too low. Australian mothers assume a disproportionate and unfair share of the costs of raising children. While some might say such specialisation is ‘their choice’, it is a highly constrained choice. Given more options, many mothers would prefer to share both the financial and the time costs of rearing children more equally.

Liberal feminists promote a ‘what’s good for the gander is good for the goose’ strategy in which women adopt a traditionally masculine lifestyle without the support of a full-time homemaker, and the ‘mums stay home’ strategy reinforces a division of labour disadvantages women and impedes fathers’ active participation family care.

The alternative is to modify paid work in ways that make it easier for everyone to combine it with care activities, reducing the standard length of the work week and ensuring more flexible work schedules. Women tend to think in terms of five distinct life stages: schooling, paid employment, family care, more paid employment, and retirement. Men think in similar terms, but with no specific time out for family care. Why not blend all these stages a bit more, making it easier to combine these activities rather than to specialise in one at each stage?

In addition to creating more time for care activities, such a reorganisation would make it easier for young people to combine paid employment with higher education. It would also make it easier for individuals to engage in the kind of lifelong learning necessary to high productivity in an era of rapid technological change.

Many people might be willing to postpone their retirement from paid employment by several years if that paid employment were less stressful and demanding, so some improvement could come even without any reduction in paid work hours. The details of this alternative have yet to be worked out through a combination of rules, tax incentives, and new cultural norms. But some promising inroads are being made in this area.

This will be a difficult and contentious journey. But as we set out on it, with Magic Pudding, we should remember that Bunyip Bluegum, darling little bear that he is, is perfectly capable of helping to cook and replenish the pudding that he likes so much to eat. I urge Australians to participate actively in the process of further developing this vision of a dual earner/dual carer economy.

  1. Pages:
  2. 1
  3. 2
  4. All

This is an edited extract from a speech to the Australia Institute, "Sharing the Care: Feminism and Family Policy in the U.S. and Australia", given on March 12, 2002. The full text can be downloaded from here.



Discuss in our Forums

See what other readers are saying about this article!

Click here to read & post comments.

Share this:
reddit this reddit thisbookmark with del.icio.us Del.icio.usdigg thisseed newsvineSeed NewsvineStumbleUpon StumbleUponsubmit to propellerkwoff it

About the Author

Professor Nancy Folbre is a visiting scholar to the Australian National University, a feminist economist and acclaimed author of ‘The Invisible Heart’.

Related Links
Australian National University
The Australia Institute
Article Tools
Comment Comments
Print Printable version
Subscribe Subscribe
Email Email a friend
Advertisement

About Us Search Discuss Feedback Legals Privacy