Hitherto, Australian climate policy “debates” have been conducted under very restrictive, paternalistic, terms of reference. “Official family” modelling of the CPRS was based on idealistic, not real-world, assumptions. The question of how best to achieve a given emissions reduction was suppressed.
The Climate Change Committee can operate differently - if it wants to.
I think there are important “process” matters determining whether the Committee’s work is productive.
Advertisement
First, the Committee should commission research from an independent agency to evaluate the effectiveness of alternative policies for pricing emissions. This would allow the various options to be ranked on the basis of their “bang for buck” emissions reduction outcomes.
Specifically, this exercise should guide the Committee in choosing which policy option produces the largest emissions reduction for the cost involved. Alternatively it could rank options based on which achieves a target emissions reduction for the lowest emissions price.
I think the Productivity Commission is ideally placed to undertake this “keystone” policy analysis. The analysis should be published for community education, consideration and debate.
Second, I assume the Committee is working towards a policy that Australia could adopt unilaterally. This is realistic. Ever since Rio, and certainly since Kyoto and Copenhagen, everybody knows that a global deal where all countries act simultaneously is not on. Differentiated national action, both as to timing and scope, is the only realistic option.
Accordingly, policy options for pricing emissions should be evaluated not only from a cost-effectiveness viewpoint, but also by whether or not they are trade competitiveness-neutral.
“First movers” in pricing emissions should not have to face reduced competitiveness versus others not acting. That sets up incentives for nobody to go first (or only to adopt sham versions of emissions pricing). It also encourages others to delay action or never to act at all.
Advertisement
The global emissions outcome of adverse competitiveness effects can be increased emissions, rather than reductions. Moreover, those acting and reducing emissions (as activity shifts to other countries) can end up actually increasing their consumption of emissions by importing them, as Dieter Helm of Oxford University recently pointed out for the United Kingdom.
Pricing emissions on a national basis must be trade competitiveness-neutral. Otherwise, the chances of a global deal will be as slim as the evidence of the past 20 years has demonstrated. If this criterion is not met in the Committee’s policy recommendations, Australia should take no action before others.
Third, the Committee’s work should be linked to the Tax Summit on the Henry Report. This opens up some important matters that can debunk the notion of a carbon tax as a “great big new tax on everything”.
For example, it allows consideration of increased reliance on consumption taxes and reduced reliance on income taxes (as recommended by the IMF) to leave real after tax incomes unchanged while increasing emissions prices. The increased reliance on consumption taxes is a way of increasing GST-like taxes, where “consumption” is consumption of emissions. Overall tax burdens shouldn’t increase.
Discuss in our Forums
See what other readers are saying about this article!
Click here to read & post comments.
7 posts so far.